Enron Mail

From:sean.crandall@enron.com
To:alan.comnes@enron.com
Subject:RE: Request for clarificatiobn of FERC order
Cc:tim.belden@enron.com
Bcc:tim.belden@enron.com
Date:Tue, 10 Jul 2001 16:45:13 -0700 (PDT)

Here are my comments

1. I wouldn't agree the caps have hurt liquidity. In fact, in the Northwe=
st at least, they have actually increased liquidity. Any decrease in liqui=
dity can be attributed primarily to a couple of things (1) uncertainty abou=
t the level of the cap and (2) when the day-ahead prices trade above the ca=
p (removing marketers as sellers).

I would propose the following cap timelines. First of all, I think it's im=
portant that FERC realize the "spot" market really is two separate markets,=
what we call the "day-ahead" cash markets, and "day-of" real-time markets.=
The 24-hour designation doesn't dovetail with the current market timeline=
s and is a source of confusion that can adversely affect liquidity and disp=
atch of power plants. For example, day-ahead cash typically trades from 6:=
00 am to approximately 7:00 am for next day deliveries. However, on Thursd=
ays the WSCC OTC market trades for Friday and Saturday deliveries, and on F=
ridays, we trade for Sunday and Monday (all of this can be adjusted for var=
ious reasons, but this is the typical schedule). If we held to the 24-hour=
spot cap literally, then Tuesday thru Friday the cap would apply to the da=
y-ahead market, but would not apply to Saturday and Monday. This obviously=
cannot be an intended consequence. I recommend the cap timeline be consis=
tent with the day-ahead WSCC OTC trading timelines.

In addition, there is some question with respect to what cap applies to the=
day-ahead market. What if the forecast calls for much higher temperatures=
and it is assured that real-time markets will be trading above the 85% thr=
eshold? Assume that stage I, II or even III is a certainty. It seems prud=
ent that a higher day-ahead price cap be established (still consistent with=
FERC's guidelines). Why? Because you would want units prescheduled to ha=
ve high reserve margins going into real-time, rather than scrambling to dis=
patch units real-time. It seems like it would be prudent for some independ=
ent board to set the day-ahead price cap equal to either the 85% or Stage I=
limit prior to trading time. This board would have to have regional repre=
sentatives in order to be truly effective. Establishing the cap does not h=
ave to be cumbersome or time consuming, in fact, it should be fairly easy.

The cap governing real-time transactions is clear. However, what isn't cle=
ar is what happens when the new Stage I cap is actually lower than the exis=
ting 85% of stage I cap. For example, during the first couple of days in J=
uly the real-time cap was operating under the 85% of Stage 1 criteria, appr=
oximately $92. The ISO hit a Stage I and Stage II and the price actually f=
ell to the $70s. This created uncertainty exactly when it shouldn't happen=
. As a result supply was apparently affected in California and the Southwe=
st for a few hours across the peak. It seems odd that prices should fall r=
eal-time as reserve margins decrease. One could argue this is a good reaso=
n why caps should be tied to daily gas prices, but assuming that isn't an o=
ption, I propose something like this: The DAY BEFORE (around 2200) the CAI=
SO, or preferably an independent body, would determine the real-time non-St=
age cap as well as a Stage minimum. While in a stage I, II, or III the hou=
rly price would be the HIGHER of the non-stage price cap OR the recalculate=
d Stage price. If the Stage I price turned out lower, then the non-stage p=
rice would be used for that hour, but the recalculated Stage I cap (and cor=
responding 85% price) would apply for the NEXT operating day, and for day-a=
head cash trading for the next trade day. This provides information before=
the trading period (enhancing liquidity) and eliminates strange price move=
ments during real-time. It also fits the FERC price cap paradigm.

2. Marketer prices. I think there is a clear bias against marketers in th=
e order. But given the fact it seems deliberately slanted against marketer=
s, there are clearly three areas where marketers should be allowed to recov=
er costs that are easily demonstrable. First would be losses at a tie into=
California. If we sell at the cap and incurr losses, then we can't sell a=
t the cap. Second would be the 10% credit premium. Credit issues apply wh=
ether you're a marketer or generator. Third would be call options. It see=
ms if the market trades above the cap and above the strike in a call option=
, that a party should be able to exercise and sell. I'm not sure what the =
difference between a peaking plant and a call option is.



-----Original Message-----
From: =09Comnes, Alan =20
Sent:=09Monday, July 09, 2001 5:31 PM
To:=09Yoder, Christian; Hall, Steve C.; Foster, Chris H.; Scholtes, Diana; =
Crandall, Sean; Williams III, Bill; Alonso, Tom; Fischer, Mark; Wolfe, Greg
Cc:=09Mara, Susan; Perrino, Dave; Belden, Tim
Subject:=09Request for clarificatiobn of FERC order

All:

Please review the attached rough arguments on what the FERC must do to fix =
it's current WSCC wide price mitigation mechanism.

Enron's (or its trade associations') filing(s) will attack bigger issues su=
ch as whether there should be price controls at all and whether the CAISO n=
eeds to be audited. However, assuming we are stuck with a cap, I want to p=
rovide FERC with comments that at least allows marketers to stay in busines=
s. The comments in the attached document are designed to address these "nu=
ts and bolts" issues. Formal comments are due next week but I need input f=
rom commercial folks like you by WEDNESDAY of this week.

Thanks,

Alan Comnes

<< File: FERC Rehearing Draft Portion GAC.doc <<